Dokumendiregister | Sotsiaalkindlustusamet |
Viit | 2-2/3479-1 |
Registreeritud | 30.01.2024 |
Sünkroonitud | 25.03.2024 |
Liik | Kiri SISSE |
Funktsioon | 2 Teabehaldus |
Sari | 2-2 Kirjavahetus rahvusvahelise koostöö küsimustes |
Toimik | 2-2/2024 |
Juurdepääsupiirang | Avalik |
Juurdepääsupiirang | |
Adressaat | Rahandusministeerium |
Saabumis/saatmisviis | Rahandusministeerium |
Vastutaja | Martin Pretke (SKA, Arendusosakond, Andmehalduse talitus) |
Originaal | Ava uues aknas |
From: Terje Tiitsu <[email protected]>
Sent: Tue, 30 Jan 2024 08:33:25 +0000
To: Eveli Kaup <[email protected]>
Cc: Jaanus Laane <[email protected]>; Triinu Sarapuu <[email protected]>; Tatjana Portnova <[email protected]>; Meelis Põlda <[email protected]>
Subject: Ed: ESTONIA: 2024 OECD Net Social Expenditure Questionnaire
Tere Eveli,
Palun registreeri deltas ja töövoog: Täitmiseks Meelis Põlda, teadmiseks Terje Tiitsu, Jaanus Laane.
Terje Tiitsu
Finants- ja haldusosakonna juhataja
Sotsiaalkindlustusamet
terje.tiitsu@sotsiaalkindlustusamet.ee
Saatja: Margus Tuvikene <[email protected]>
Saatmisaeg: teisipäev, 30. jaanuar 2024 10:10
Adressaat: [email protected]; Terje Tiitsu <[email protected]>; Meelis Põlda <[email protected]>; Martin Pretke <[email protected]>
Koopia: Kadri Klaos <[email protected]>
Teema: FW: ESTONIA: 2024 OECD Net Social Expenditure Questionnaire
Tähelepanu! Tegemist on väljastpoolt asutust saabunud kirjaga. Tundmatu saatja korral palume linke ja faile mitte avada. |
Tere!
Tuli taas OECD küsimustik neto sotsiaalkulude kohta, mida küsitakse üle aasta. Palun teie abi vastamisel.
Tähtaeg on 30.aprill.
Head,
Margus
From: [email protected] <[email protected]>
Sent: Monday, January 29, 2024 6:30 PM
To: Margus Tuvikene <[email protected]>; Lemmi Oro <[email protected]>
Cc: [email protected]; [email protected]; [email protected]; [email protected]; [email protected]
Subject: ESTONIA: 2024 OECD Net Social Expenditure Questionnaire
Tähelepanu! Tegemist on välisvõrgust saabunud kirjaga. |
Message on behalf of Willem Adema - further to Violet Sochay’s email on 16 January 2024:
Dear colleagues from Estonia,
The OECD Social Expenditure database (SOCX via www.oecd.org/social/expenditure.htm) contains information on public and private social expenditure in OECD countries. These gross expenditure data fail, however, to account for the impact of the tax system on spending. In this regard, there are three items that should be accounted for: direct taxation of benefit income, indirect taxation of consumption by benefit-recipients, and tax advantages with a social purpose.
Following the usual bi-annual data collection practice, please find attached the Net Social Expenditure Questionnaire to collect information on direct taxation of social cash transfers and tax breaks with a social purpose from 2020 or 2021. To facilitate the data collection process, we send you an Excel file with the relevant information as we have it for your country, and we ask you to revise existing figures (where appropriate) and provide an update with similar annual information from 2020 or 2021. Please add any further relevant information, where appropriate and/or feasible. For example, if more detail on direct taxation of cash transfers has become available, please let us know. Of course, please list new Tax Breaks with a Social Purpose and indicate which measures have ceased to exist.
For your information, the data you supply is used to calculate net social expenditure indicators as published in a statistics brief, the overview table with indicators and a detailed file with information per country. The methodology is included in the OECD SOCX Manual. New information on Net Social Expenditure will be included in the next version of the OECD Social Expenditure Database for release in Q4 2024.
Please return the completed/updated files to Pauline Fron ([email protected] ), Maxime Ladaique ([email protected] ) or myself ([email protected] ) by Tuesday 30th April 2024.
Should you have any questions about the questionnaire. please do not hesitate to contact Pauline, Maxime or myself.
Many thanks for your cooperation in helping us to continue to improve Net SOCX data quality.
With best wishes,
Willem Adema, D.Phil | |
2, rue André Pascal - 75775 Paris Cedex 16
Tel: +33 1 45 24 15 57;
http://oe.cd/ahd // http://oe.cd/ahd-fr
http://oe.cd/fdb // http://oe.cd/fdb-fr
http://oe.cd/gender // http://oe.cd/gender-fr
http://oe.cd/socx // http://oe.cd/socx-fr
P Säästa loodust ja ära prindi seda e-kirja!
Käesolev e-kiri võib sisaldada asutusesiseseks kasutamiseks tunnistatud teavet.
This e-mail may contain information which is classified for official use.
1
NET SOCIAL EXPENDITURE INDICATORS: QUESTIONNAIRE
1. Introduction
1. The OECD Social Expenditure database (SOCX) contains information on public and private
social expenditure in OECD countries (Public social expenditure reflects budgetary resource allocation by
general government (i.e. different levels of government and social security funds), as for example old-age
cash benefits and housing allowances. Private social expenditure involves mandatory private social
protection arrangements that although legislated are not financed through funds that are part of general
government. Voluntary private social expenditure includes benefits accruing from privately operated
programmes that involve the redistribution of resources across households as well as benefits accruing
from tax advantaged individual and collective plans (often towards pension or health coverage).
2. These gross expenditure data fail, however, to account for the impact of the tax system on
spending. In this regard, there are three items that should be accounted for:
1. Tax advantages with a social purpose;
2. Direct taxation of benefit income;
3. Indirect taxation of consumption by benefit-recipients.
As the impact of each of these three items differs markedly across countries, a comparison of gross social
expenditure to GDP ratios can lead to misleading analysis of public social effort across countries. Further
details are provided in, for example, DAFFE/CFA/WP2(2002)33, Adema, Fron and Ladaique, 2011 or see
section 5. Net (after tax) social expenditure in the OECD SOCX Manual 2019 Edition: A guide to the
OECD Social Expenditure Database.
3. At their meetings in November 2002 and June 2003, delegates to the Committee on Fiscal
Affair’s Working Party No. 2 on Tax Policy Analysis and Tax Statistics, agreed to collect relevant
information for all OECD countries. Such information was last gathered in 2022 for years 2018/19 for all
38 OECD countries. Following the usual bi-annual data collection practice, this new version of the
questionnaire intends to gather information on direct taxation and tax breaks with a social purpose for 2020
to 2022. Countries are asked to return the completed questionnaire by Tuesday 30th April 2024.
4. This document first provides a concise summary of what social expenditure involves. Then, in
section 3, it provides an overview of the framework for calculating net (after tax) social expenditure
indicators. Section 4 sets out the type of information we would like to obtain from you for 2020-22.
2
2. Defining Social expenditure
5. The OECD defines social expenditures as:
The provision by public and private institutions of benefits to, and financial contributions
targeted at, households and individuals in order to provide support during circumstances which
adversely affect their welfare. Provided that the provision of the benefits and financial
contributions constitutes neither a direct payment for a particular good or service nor an
individual contract or transfer. Such benefits can be cash transfers, or can be the direct (in-kind)
provision of goods and services. Since only benefits provided by institutions are included,
transfers between households - albeit of a social nature, are not.
Social expenditure1 includes cash benefits (e.g. unemployment benefit), social services (e.g. daycare
subsidies) and tax breaks with a social purpose (e.g. tax expenditures towards families with children).
However, these tax breaks with a social purpose are generally not included in public social expenditure
totals in the National Accounts or the OECD Social Expenditure Database (SOCX).
2.1 Social vis-à-vis non social
6. Two main criteria have to be simultaneously satisfied for some expenditure item to be classified
as “social”. First, the benefits have to be intended to address one or more social purposes. Second, In order
to be considered social, programmes regulating the provision of benefits have to involve a) inter-personal
redistribution, or b) compulsory participation.
7. The purpose of the benefits is one factor in the delineation of what is social and what not. The
OECD Social Expenditure Database groups benefits with a social purpose in 9 policy areas: old-age,
survivors, incapacity related benefits, health, family, active labour market policies, unemployment
compensation, housing and other contingencies, e.g., cash transfers to those with low incomes (OECD
SOCX Manual 2019 Edition: A guide to the OECD Social Expenditure Database ). In most OECD
countries, public benefits cover most, if not all, of the aforementioned policy areas. On the other hand,
public support to general savings programmes or life insurance policies are not considered social, and
while fiscal support towards children is considered social, favourable tax-treatment because of marital
status is not.
8. Benefits are “social” if entitlement to receive benefits with a social purpose involves the inter-
personal redistribution of resources among programme participants or compulsory participation. If benefits
are the result of direct market transactions by individuals given their individual risk profiles, then the
payment is not social, even though its purpose may be. Thus, individual pension plans taken out at
prevailing market prices that are not subject to compulsion or redistribution (e.g. without fiscal support) are
not considered social. By contrast, public benefits with a social purpose practically always involve
redistribution across households, as they are either financed through general taxation or compulsory social
security contributions, leading to the redistribution of resources across the population or within population
groups (e.g. all adherents to an unemployment insurance fund).
1. Social expenditure or social spending concerns an aggregate of all (or a group of) social benefits. It does
not include contributions and other payments by households that finance social programmes. Such
payments are considered to be “social contributions”.
3
2.2 Public vis-à-vis private social expenditure
9. The distinction between public and private is on the basis of who controls the relevant financial
flows; public institutions or private bodies. Social benefits are regarded as public when general government
(that is central, state, and local governments, including social security funds) controls relevant financial
flows. Sickness benefits financed by mandatory employer and employee contributions to social insurance
funds (receipts) are by convention considered public. All social benefits not provided by general
government are within the private domain.
10. Within the group of private social benefits, a further distinction is made concerning the nature of
provision. Sometimes, governments mandate - force by legislation, employers to provide benefits to their
employees, or mandate individuals and/or employers to make contributions to private funds from which
benefits accrue. All such benefits are regarded as mandatory private social benefits. Private benefits with a
social purpose made by employers on a voluntary basis or that do not derive from mandatory contributions
to insurance plans that redistribute resources among the insured population, are considered voluntary.
Table 1: Some examples of benefits with a social purpose
Social policy area Spending item
Public (Different levels of government,
including social insurance funds)
Old age Old-age cash benefits
Services to the elderly
Age-related tax allowances
Mandatory private (employers, private
funds)
Incapacity-related Legislated continued (partial) wage-payments
in case of absence due to illness
Legislated occupational injury benefits paid by
private funds
Voluntary private (employers, private
funds)
Health Employer-financed health insurance or
occupational pensions
Other contingencies Welfare services provided by NGOs
3. A concise overview of Net Social Expenditure adjustments2
11. Gross social expenditure data can give a misleading picture of social effort across countries as
they do not account for the impact of tax systems. In this context, there are broadly speaking three features
that play an important role.
3.1 Direct taxation and social security contributions on transfers
12. In some OECD countries almost all benefits are paid net of tax; in others most benefit income is
taxed in the same way as income from work. Similarly, there are marked differences in the taxation of
benefit types. Benefits for families with children are generally not taxed, even when other transfer income
is taxed in line with earnings. Thus, there is considerable variation in the extent of taxation across countries
and across different types of benefit income.
13. In countries where governments levy direct income tax and social security contributions on cash
transfers to beneficiaries, social spending and redistribution of resources is lower than suggested by gross
spending indicators. For example, in Austria the recipient of an unemployment benefit who previously had
2. Over the years, a methodology has been developed for collating net social expenditure indicators, see
Adema, et al (1996), Adema and Einerhand (1998), Adema (1999, and 2001), and Adema and Ladaique
(2009 and 2005).
4
earnings equivalent to average earnings and who lives in a couple-family with two young children received
approximately the equivalent of EUR 19 100 in 2020, on which he or she did get a tax credit of EUR 700.
By contrast, a similar person in Sweden received approximately annual income support of EUR 23 700 but
paid EUR 7 000 in income taxes and social-security contributions so that net benefit income was EUR
16 700 (On-line Tax-Benefit calculator via www.oecd.org/els/social/workincentives). Thus, net income for
such a family in Sweden is lower than in Austria, although gross income was much higher. In aggregate
spending terms, this means that countries that tax transfer incomes rather heavily divert a significant part of
transferred income to flow back into the coffers of the Treasury. As a result, net (after tax) public spending
on unemployment benefits is about 75% of the level suggested by gross indicators in Sweden.
3.2 Indirect taxes on consumption out of benefit income.
14. Recipients of social benefits generally use their benefit income to finance consumption of goods
and services, much of which is subject to consumption taxes. For example, in Germany in 2010, duties on
coffee amounted to just under EUR 1.0 billion (OECD, 2012b), part of which was paid by benefit
recipients. Consumption taxes reduce the real value of consumption which can be financed out of a given
level of benefits; establish another flow of back in tax receipts to the Exchequer; and, affect the gross
social spending levels. For example, in order to provide benefit recipients with a net income of 100 units, a
country like the US with an average consumption tax rate close to 4% needs to pay a gross benefit of about
104 units. In EU-countries, where the average consumption tax rate is around 20% a gross payment would
have to be around 125 units to have an equivalent net value. Thus, gross spending totals in the US can be
somewhat lower than in EU-countries while generating a similar net value for benefit-recipients.
3.3 Tax breaks for social purposes.
15. Many governments of OECD countries pursue social policy objectives through the tax system.
Two main types of such measures can be distinguished. One is reduced taxation on particular sources of
income or types of household (e.g. an age-related tax allowance). This sort of tax relief is equivalent to a
variation in direct taxation of benefit income, and it is thus not necessary to account for these again. For
example, income tax exemptions for those receiving “Long-term incapacity benefit” in the
United Kingdom are accounted for while establishing the amount of direct taxes paid on benefit income. In
general, exemptions of benefits from taxation are not recorded again in as TBSP.
16. The second group of tax measures with social effects concern Tax Breaks for Social Purposes
(TBSPs) and are defined as:
“those reductions, exemptions, deductions or postponements of taxes, which: a) perform the
same policy function as transfer payments which, if they existed, would be classified as
social expenditures; or b) are aimed at stimulating private provision of benefits".
17. Tax breaks which mirror the effect of cash benefits often concern fiscal support to families with
children. Such support can be provided in different forms. First, tax systems may include tax credits for
children or associated costs (e.g. childcare-related tax credits). Sometimes, cash transfers and fiscal support
are part of one and the same programme. For example, tax relief in Germany for families with children
amounted to EUR 46.2 billion in 2019, of which EUR 27.2 billion was off-set against tax liabilities (and
thus recorded as a TBSP) and EUR 19.0 billion paid out in transfer income – to be recorded as a cash
transfer in the OECD Social Expenditure Database. The United States’ Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC)
is similar in providing benefits partly as a TBSP and partly as cash transfers.
18. Second, in many OECD countries children are included in the tax unit, benefiting the household
in question. Such measures are not a deviation from the national standard tax system, and thus may not be
5
considered as “tax expenditures” (OECD, 1996). Nevertheless, such support is clearly important, and an
estimate on the value of revenue foregone provides a useful indicator of financial support to children in
society, and so should be included in reported TBSPs.
19. Tax breaks for social purposes can also be granted with the aim to stimulate private social
protection. In addition to tax reliefs for individuals and employers who contribute to private social
insurance funds, such fiscal measures can include exemptions of donations to non-government
organisations that provide social services or support to employers for different reasons, e.g. when
supporting employee childcare needs or health coverage, or when hiring long-term unemployed workers,
etc.
4. Request for Data
20. This section discusses the type of information that we would like to obtain from countries. The
items to be considered are:
− Direct taxation of benefits;
− Tax breaks for social purposes;
4.1 Direct taxes and social security contributions on transfers
21. Across countries, information on direct tax (including Soc. Sec. Cont.) on transfer income can be
obtained from a variety of sources. These include: official administrative information; microsimulation
models based on annual income or monthly income; microsimulation based on survey data; adjustments
made on the basis of average tax rates based on microdatasets.
4.1.1 Administrative data
22. Ideally, administrative data is the preferred source of information of tax paid on benefit income
as such information is likely to be the most reliable. It may be feasible to obtain such information when
national social protection systems involve only a few taxable benefits (e.g. Germany), and/or when
completed tax forms allow for identification of tax paid on (some specified items of) transfer income. Also,
administrative information may give a picture of the aggregate of taxes paid on all public social cash
transfers, but not facilitate an allocation of tax paid on different types of transfers (e.g. unemployment vis-
à-vis pension benefits).
6
Question 1: Do you have administrative information on direct tax (including social security
contributions) paid on transfer income by benefit recipients. If yes, please complete Table Q1?
Table Q1.
Tax paid by benefit recipients on transfer income,
2020 to 2022
Amount
(in national currency)
Total tax paid (including soc. sec. cont.) on public1 transfer
income
of which:
- Income tax
- Social security contributions
Total tax paid (including soc. sec. cont.) on private1 transfer
income
of which:
- Income tax
- Social security contributions
1) Public transfer income concerns all cash benefits paid by general government (different levels of
government and social security institutions). Other social benefits, e.g. occupational pension
payments, are considered private.
Question 2: Do you have administrative information on direct tax (including social security
contributions) paid on specified transfer income items? If yes, please complete Table Q2 by
providing information at the greatest possible level of detail (e.g. by items as listed in Table Q3).
Table Q2.
Tax paid by benefit recipients on specific transfer income items,
2020 to 2022
Amount of tax
(including soc. sec. cont.) paid
(in national currency)
Total tax paid (including soc. sec. cont.) on transfer income
- item 1…
- item 2…
- item 3…
- etc.
For example, on basis of the US income-tax form, one could think of the
following list of items:
Total tax paid (including soc. sec. cont.) on transfer income
- item 1… - all social security benefits (OASDI)
- item 2… - unemployment compensation
- item 3… - pensions and annuities
- item 4 - Tax-advantaged individual retirement accounts
7
4.1.2 Estimates based on microdata sets
23. In the absence of administrative data, “microsimulation-models” and micro data sets (e.g. the
survey of personal incomes for the UK) which contain detailed information on both the incomes received
by households and their taxation can be used to generate average itemised tax rates (AITRs): e.g. the
average tax rate on public pension benefit or unemployment benefits. Indeed, the concept of AITRs has
been developed to facilitate identification of different tax levies on different social benefits. The AITR can
be defined as the total taxes paid by those receiving a given benefit, divided by the total income (from all
sources) of those receiving that benefit. Formally, the relevant calculations are:
AITR i = tu =1, n TI i/ tu=1, n I i
where: I is the amount of income-type “i”, and TI is the amount of tax paid on that particular amount of income, “i” is
the type or category of income, “tu” is a tax unit with income-type “i”, and “n” is the number of tax units in the
sample with income of type “i”. The broad income categories “i” include old-age cash benefits, unemployment
compensation, wage income, etc (see table Q3).
24. As is clear from the formula, calculation of the AITR requires information on the tax paid on
each particular benefit. If a given benefit is subject to a constant tax rate (possibly zero), this information is
straightforward to calculate. However, if it is subject to a progressive tax schedule (possibly applied to the
total of several income sources), the calculation needs more care. The methodology that we ask countries
to follow is to calculate the average tax rate a particular household faces on that income (or group of
incomes), as illustrated in Annex 1. This tax rate is applied to all household benefit income subject to the
progressive schedule. This methodology does not imply an ordering of different parts of income nor does it
require a more or less arbitrary decision on what part of household income should be “taxed” at a higher or
lower rate.
25. Depending on the nature of national social protection systems (the number of different social
programmes and taxable benefit payments) and the nature of information in microdatasets, the number of
identifiable AITRs will vary from country to country. Please complete Table Q3 in line with what is
possible given the source of information to which you have access.
Question 3: If your country has many taxable benefit items and administrative data do not allow for
identification of tax paid by benefit recipients of broad income groups, we ask you to generate
Average Itemised Tax rates per social expenditure programme (example line 1a in Table Q3) or
if this level of detail is not available the suggested broad social expenditure categories (for
example line 1 in Table Q3).
8
Table Q3.
Average Itemised Tax Rates,
2020 to 2022
Item
n° Broad Income Category 'i' 1
AITR
(%)
Amount of tax
(including soc. sec. cont.) paid
(in national currency)
1 Old-age cash benefits
1a - public pensions 2
1b - early retirement benefits
1c - private pensions 3
2 Survivors' benefits
2a - public pensions 2
2b - private pensions 3
3 Incapacity-related benefits
3a - Disability pensions
3b - Occupational Injury benefits
3c - Sickness payments 4
4 Family cash benefits
4a - Family benefits
4b - Maternity and parental leave payments
4c - Sole parent benefits
5 Active labour market policies
5a - benefits while on training
6 Unemployment
6a - unemployment insurance benefit
6b - unemployment assistance benefit
7 Housing
7a - rent subsidies
8 Other contingencies
8a - Low Income benefits
9 Wage income 5
1) Certain broad income categories may not apply to your country, please indicate. Not dissimilarly,
please indicate if pension income includes old-age cash benefits, survivor benefits and/or disability
pensions.
2) Public transfer income concerns all cash benefits paid by general government (different levels of
government and social security institutions). Other social benefits, e.g. occupational pension payments,
are considered private.
3) All pension income (old-age cash benefits) paid by the state or a social security fund.
4) If sickness benefits paid through social insurance funds (please indicate whether or not his covers
maternity and parental benefits in your data-set).
9
5) This category is included for reference purposes, but can be used to estimate tax paid by recipients of
continued wage payments in case of absence because of illness.
26. In some countries, ignoring local taxation may lead to underestimating the value of tax paid by
benefit recipients. In such cases, the preferred option is to “model” the situation analogous to Taxing
Wages (OECD, 2023). For example, for Switzerland, the situation in Canton Zürich could be used to
generate AITRs.
27. These AITRs are subsequently applied to the relevant spending items in the OECD Social
Expenditure Database leading to estimates of tax paid on particular spending items. Information derived
from microsimulation models/micro data sets can also be used to verify available administrative
information, or enrich it by adding more detail to its aggregate nature (see the previous section). In general,
the Secretariat will only publish aggregate indicators on net social expenditure, and differences taxes paid
across broad social expenditure items to illustrate the different tax burdens on different benefits.
4.2 Tax breaks with a social purpose
28. Please provide information on the revenue foregone of TBSPs other than pensions (see below) in
as much detail as possible in Table Q4, which includes different examples from different countries.
Question 4: Please provide information on the revenue foregone (accruals basis) of Tax Breaks for Social
Purposes in your country in Table Q4. Please note if you have already accounted for a Tax
breaks that is similar to cash benefits in the direct tax calculations, there is no need to record this
item again. If appropriate, please do include information on provincial and/or municipal TBSPs
and the revenue foregone related to including children in the tax unit.
10
Table Q4.
The value of Tax breaks for social purposes,
2020 to 2022
11
4.2.1 Tax treatment of pensions
29. The notion of tax breaks with a social purpose includes those measures aimed at stimulating
private pension take-up. However, tax breaks on occupational and individual pension programmes are
difficult to deal with as intervention (taxation and/or tax reliefs) occurs at, various stages of this form of
contractual savings. Tax treatment needs to be considered in three different areas:
30. Due to the complexity of calculations arising from these issues, there is no comparable data-set
available on the value of tax advantages on pensions. Nevertheless, available information suggests,
however, that the value of favourable tax-treatment of private pension arrangements can be considerable.
For example, in Germany and the United States such favourable tax treatment pensions was worth about
1% of GDP in 2019 and accounted for about 2% of GDP in Australia.( see detailed information on the
impact of the tax system on social expenditure by country) We would like to present the cost to public
budgets of the current tax system in the current financial year on tax breaks for pensions, regardless of
what effects the current tax system may have on revenues in future years. Because of the limitations in
comparability of information, such information would be presented as a memorandum item only.
Question 5: Please provide information on the revenue foregone (accruals basis) of Tax Breaks for
Pensions in your country in Table Q5.
Table Q5.
The value of Tax breaks for pensions,
2020 to 2022
− Contributions to programmes could be by employers or employees, out of taxed or untaxed income;
− The funds which invest the pension contributions on behalf of those contributing could be taxed or
untaxed;
− The payment of pension or annuity or lump-sum benefits at the end of the contributions period could
be taxed or untaxed.
12
ANNEX 1: AN EXAMPLE OF CALCULATING AVERAGE ITEMISED TAX RATES
Microsimulation models underlie the estimates on direct taxation of benefits in many countries,
especially when most transfer income is tax (e.g. Denmark and Sweden). It is relatively straightforward to
calculate average itemised tax rates (AITRs) on benefit income if households have only one source of
income. For example, if a retiree receives pension income worth 100 units at the “standard” tax rate of
20%, net transfer income is 80 units, and if all households were the same (and had no income from other
sources) the AITR on public pension income would be 20%. If the retiree were to receive non-taxable child
benefit, that income would be disregarded for the calculation of the tax rate on his/her household income,
while the AITR on child benefit would be nil for that country. It may well be that for older retirees (e.g.
over 75) a more favourable tax rate applies. If possible, it would be preferable to account for this age-
related measure while calculating the household tax rate, rather than it being separately treated as a tax
break with a social purpose.
Frequently pensioners receive income from different sources. Consider the case of a retiree who also
receives a supplementary (private) pension worth 50 Units. In the absence of progressivity in the tax
system, the household tax rate remains as before. However, the substantial increase of income may well
lead to the retiree being in a higher tax bracket, so that the “average” tax rate increases. This “higher” tax
rate is applied to all household income: different tax rates are not applied to different parts of household
income. (If the retiree were to receive child benefit that would be taxed at the same rate, unless the tax
benefit system explicitly regards this income as non-taxable). Thus, the methodology does not imply an
ordering of different parts of income, whereby different income sources are taxed differently according to
an arbitrary decision on which part of income is “basic” or “supplementary” (see Table A1). Differences in
AITRs are thus associated with income groupings wherein benefit recipients typically find themselves.
Table A1. Example of calculating AITRs on two types of income
household Basic
pension
Supplementary
pension
Total
household
income
Income
tax rate
Tax paid Allocation of tax over
pension income
components
Basic Supplementary
1 50 25 75 10% 7.5 5.0 2.5
2 75 50 125 15% 13.8 8.3 5.5
3 100 0 100 10% 10.0 10.0 0.0
4 50 100 150 15% 17.5 5.8 11.7
5 50 250 300 15% 40.0 6.7 33.3
Total 325 425 750 88.8 35.8 53
AITR basic pension income = tax paid over basic pension/total basic pension
income
11.1%
AITR supplementary pension income = tax paid over supplementary
pension/total supplementary pension income
12.5%
Assumed: standard tax rate is 10% when Income is less than 100 Units, and 15% of income over and above the 100 unit threshold.
13
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Adema, W., B. Eklind, J. Lotz, M. Einerhand and M. Pearson (1996), “Net Public Social Expenditure”,
Labour Market and Social Policy Occasional Papers, No. 19, OECD, Paris.
Adema, W. and M. Einerhand (1998), “The Growing Role of Private Social Benefits”, Labour Market and
Social Policy Occasional Paper, No. 32, OECD, Paris.
Adema, W. (1999), “Net Social Expenditure”, Labour Market and Social Policy Occasional Paper, No.
39, OECD, Paris
Adema, W. (2001), “Net Social Expenditure – 2nd edition”, Labour Market and Social Policy Occasional
Papers, No. 52, OECD, Paris.
Adema, W. and M. Ladaique (2005), “Net Social Expenditure, 2005 Edition”, Social, Employment and
Migration Working Papers, No. 29, Paris (www.oecd.org/els/workingpapers).
Adema, W. and M. Ladaique (2009), “How Expensive is the Welfare State? Gross and Net Indicators in
the OECD Social Expenditure Database (SOCX)”, OECD Social, Employment and Migration
Working Papers No. 92.
Adema, W, P.Fron and M. Ladaique (2011), Is the European Welfare State Really More Expensive?
Indicators on Social Spending, 1980-2012; and a Manual to the OECD Social Expenditure Database
(SOCX) Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers, No. 124, Paris
(www.oecd.org/social/expenditure.htm).
Adema, W, P.Fron (2019), The OECD SOCX Manual – 2019 edition
A guide to the OECD Social Expenditure Database (www.oecd.org/social/expenditure.htm)
OECD (1996), Tax Expenditures: Recent Experiences, Paris.
OECD (2023), Benefits and Wages, OECD, Paris and On-line Tax-Benefit calculator via
www.oecd.org/els/social/workincentives .
OECD (2023), The OECD Social Expenditure database (SOCX), www.oecd.org/social/expenditure.htm.
OECD (2023), Taxing Wages, Paris. (https://www.oecd.org/tax/taxing-wages-20725124.htm )
OECD (2023), Revenue Statistics 2023: Tax Revenue Buoyancy in OECD Countries, OECD Publishing,
Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/2522770x.
1
NET SOCIAL EXPENDITURE INDICATORS: QUESTIONNAIRE
1. Introduction
1. The OECD Social Expenditure database (SOCX) contains information on public and private
social expenditure in OECD countries (Public social expenditure reflects budgetary resource allocation by
general government (i.e. different levels of government and social security funds), as for example old-age
cash benefits and housing allowances. Private social expenditure involves mandatory private social
protection arrangements that although legislated are not financed through funds that are part of general
government. Voluntary private social expenditure includes benefits accruing from privately operated
programmes that involve the redistribution of resources across households as well as benefits accruing
from tax advantaged individual and collective plans (often towards pension or health coverage).
2. These gross expenditure data fail, however, to account for the impact of the tax system on
spending. In this regard, there are three items that should be accounted for:
1. Tax advantages with a social purpose;
2. Direct taxation of benefit income;
3. Indirect taxation of consumption by benefit-recipients.
As the impact of each of these three items differs markedly across countries, a comparison of gross social
expenditure to GDP ratios can lead to misleading analysis of public social effort across countries. Further
details are provided in, for example, DAFFE/CFA/WP2(2002)33, Adema, Fron and Ladaique, 2011 or see
section 5. Net (after tax) social expenditure in the OECD SOCX Manual 2019 Edition: A guide to the
OECD Social Expenditure Database.
3. At their meetings in November 2002 and June 2003, delegates to the Committee on Fiscal
Affair’s Working Party No. 2 on Tax Policy Analysis and Tax Statistics, agreed to collect relevant
information for all OECD countries. Such information was last gathered in 2022 for years 2018/19 for all
38 OECD countries. Following the usual bi-annual data collection practice, this new version of the
questionnaire intends to gather information on direct taxation and tax breaks with a social purpose for 2020
to 2022. Countries are asked to return the completed questionnaire by Tuesday 30th April 2024.
4. This document first provides a concise summary of what social expenditure involves. Then, in
section 3, it provides an overview of the framework for calculating net (after tax) social expenditure
indicators. Section 4 sets out the type of information we would like to obtain from you for 2020-22.
2
2. Defining Social expenditure
5. The OECD defines social expenditures as:
The provision by public and private institutions of benefits to, and financial contributions
targeted at, households and individuals in order to provide support during circumstances which
adversely affect their welfare. Provided that the provision of the benefits and financial
contributions constitutes neither a direct payment for a particular good or service nor an
individual contract or transfer. Such benefits can be cash transfers, or can be the direct (in-kind)
provision of goods and services. Since only benefits provided by institutions are included,
transfers between households - albeit of a social nature, are not.
Social expenditure1 includes cash benefits (e.g. unemployment benefit), social services (e.g. daycare
subsidies) and tax breaks with a social purpose (e.g. tax expenditures towards families with children).
However, these tax breaks with a social purpose are generally not included in public social expenditure
totals in the National Accounts or the OECD Social Expenditure Database (SOCX).
2.1 Social vis-à-vis non social
6. Two main criteria have to be simultaneously satisfied for some expenditure item to be classified
as “social”. First, the benefits have to be intended to address one or more social purposes. Second, In order
to be considered social, programmes regulating the provision of benefits have to involve a) inter-personal
redistribution, or b) compulsory participation.
7. The purpose of the benefits is one factor in the delineation of what is social and what not. The
OECD Social Expenditure Database groups benefits with a social purpose in 9 policy areas: old-age,
survivors, incapacity related benefits, health, family, active labour market policies, unemployment
compensation, housing and other contingencies, e.g., cash transfers to those with low incomes (OECD
SOCX Manual 2019 Edition: A guide to the OECD Social Expenditure Database ). In most OECD
countries, public benefits cover most, if not all, of the aforementioned policy areas. On the other hand,
public support to general savings programmes or life insurance policies are not considered social, and
while fiscal support towards children is considered social, favourable tax-treatment because of marital
status is not.
8. Benefits are “social” if entitlement to receive benefits with a social purpose involves the inter-
personal redistribution of resources among programme participants or compulsory participation. If benefits
are the result of direct market transactions by individuals given their individual risk profiles, then the
payment is not social, even though its purpose may be. Thus, individual pension plans taken out at
prevailing market prices that are not subject to compulsion or redistribution (e.g. without fiscal support) are
not considered social. By contrast, public benefits with a social purpose practically always involve
redistribution across households, as they are either financed through general taxation or compulsory social
security contributions, leading to the redistribution of resources across the population or within population
groups (e.g. all adherents to an unemployment insurance fund).
1. Social expenditure or social spending concerns an aggregate of all (or a group of) social benefits. It does
not include contributions and other payments by households that finance social programmes. Such
payments are considered to be “social contributions”.
3
2.2 Public vis-à-vis private social expenditure
9. The distinction between public and private is on the basis of who controls the relevant financial
flows; public institutions or private bodies. Social benefits are regarded as public when general government
(that is central, state, and local governments, including social security funds) controls relevant financial
flows. Sickness benefits financed by mandatory employer and employee contributions to social insurance
funds (receipts) are by convention considered public. All social benefits not provided by general
government are within the private domain.
10. Within the group of private social benefits, a further distinction is made concerning the nature of
provision. Sometimes, governments mandate - force by legislation, employers to provide benefits to their
employees, or mandate individuals and/or employers to make contributions to private funds from which
benefits accrue. All such benefits are regarded as mandatory private social benefits. Private benefits with a
social purpose made by employers on a voluntary basis or that do not derive from mandatory contributions
to insurance plans that redistribute resources among the insured population, are considered voluntary.
Table 1: Some examples of benefits with a social purpose
Social policy area Spending item
Public (Different levels of government,
including social insurance funds)
Old age Old-age cash benefits
Services to the elderly
Age-related tax allowances
Mandatory private (employers, private
funds)
Incapacity-related Legislated continued (partial) wage-payments
in case of absence due to illness
Legislated occupational injury benefits paid by
private funds
Voluntary private (employers, private
funds)
Health Employer-financed health insurance or
occupational pensions
Other contingencies Welfare services provided by NGOs
3. A concise overview of Net Social Expenditure adjustments2
11. Gross social expenditure data can give a misleading picture of social effort across countries as
they do not account for the impact of tax systems. In this context, there are broadly speaking three features
that play an important role.
3.1 Direct taxation and social security contributions on transfers
12. In some OECD countries almost all benefits are paid net of tax; in others most benefit income is
taxed in the same way as income from work. Similarly, there are marked differences in the taxation of
benefit types. Benefits for families with children are generally not taxed, even when other transfer income
is taxed in line with earnings. Thus, there is considerable variation in the extent of taxation across countries
and across different types of benefit income.
13. In countries where governments levy direct income tax and social security contributions on cash
transfers to beneficiaries, social spending and redistribution of resources is lower than suggested by gross
spending indicators. For example, in Austria the recipient of an unemployment benefit who previously had
2. Over the years, a methodology has been developed for collating net social expenditure indicators, see
Adema, et al (1996), Adema and Einerhand (1998), Adema (1999, and 2001), and Adema and Ladaique
(2009 and 2005).
4
earnings equivalent to average earnings and who lives in a couple-family with two young children received
approximately the equivalent of EUR 19 100 in 2020, on which he or she did get a tax credit of EUR 700.
By contrast, a similar person in Sweden received approximately annual income support of EUR 23 700 but
paid EUR 7 000 in income taxes and social-security contributions so that net benefit income was EUR
16 700 (On-line Tax-Benefit calculator via www.oecd.org/els/social/workincentives). Thus, net income for
such a family in Sweden is lower than in Austria, although gross income was much higher. In aggregate
spending terms, this means that countries that tax transfer incomes rather heavily divert a significant part of
transferred income to flow back into the coffers of the Treasury. As a result, net (after tax) public spending
on unemployment benefits is about 75% of the level suggested by gross indicators in Sweden.
3.2 Indirect taxes on consumption out of benefit income.
14. Recipients of social benefits generally use their benefit income to finance consumption of goods
and services, much of which is subject to consumption taxes. For example, in Germany in 2010, duties on
coffee amounted to just under EUR 1.0 billion (OECD, 2012b), part of which was paid by benefit
recipients. Consumption taxes reduce the real value of consumption which can be financed out of a given
level of benefits; establish another flow of back in tax receipts to the Exchequer; and, affect the gross
social spending levels. For example, in order to provide benefit recipients with a net income of 100 units, a
country like the US with an average consumption tax rate close to 4% needs to pay a gross benefit of about
104 units. In EU-countries, where the average consumption tax rate is around 20% a gross payment would
have to be around 125 units to have an equivalent net value. Thus, gross spending totals in the US can be
somewhat lower than in EU-countries while generating a similar net value for benefit-recipients.
3.3 Tax breaks for social purposes.
15. Many governments of OECD countries pursue social policy objectives through the tax system.
Two main types of such measures can be distinguished. One is reduced taxation on particular sources of
income or types of household (e.g. an age-related tax allowance). This sort of tax relief is equivalent to a
variation in direct taxation of benefit income, and it is thus not necessary to account for these again. For
example, income tax exemptions for those receiving “Long-term incapacity benefit” in the
United Kingdom are accounted for while establishing the amount of direct taxes paid on benefit income. In
general, exemptions of benefits from taxation are not recorded again in as TBSP.
16. The second group of tax measures with social effects concern Tax Breaks for Social Purposes
(TBSPs) and are defined as:
“those reductions, exemptions, deductions or postponements of taxes, which: a) perform the
same policy function as transfer payments which, if they existed, would be classified as
social expenditures; or b) are aimed at stimulating private provision of benefits".
17. Tax breaks which mirror the effect of cash benefits often concern fiscal support to families with
children. Such support can be provided in different forms. First, tax systems may include tax credits for
children or associated costs (e.g. childcare-related tax credits). Sometimes, cash transfers and fiscal support
are part of one and the same programme. For example, tax relief in Germany for families with children
amounted to EUR 46.2 billion in 2019, of which EUR 27.2 billion was off-set against tax liabilities (and
thus recorded as a TBSP) and EUR 19.0 billion paid out in transfer income – to be recorded as a cash
transfer in the OECD Social Expenditure Database. The United States’ Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC)
is similar in providing benefits partly as a TBSP and partly as cash transfers.
18. Second, in many OECD countries children are included in the tax unit, benefiting the household
in question. Such measures are not a deviation from the national standard tax system, and thus may not be
5
considered as “tax expenditures” (OECD, 1996). Nevertheless, such support is clearly important, and an
estimate on the value of revenue foregone provides a useful indicator of financial support to children in
society, and so should be included in reported TBSPs.
19. Tax breaks for social purposes can also be granted with the aim to stimulate private social
protection. In addition to tax reliefs for individuals and employers who contribute to private social
insurance funds, such fiscal measures can include exemptions of donations to non-government
organisations that provide social services or support to employers for different reasons, e.g. when
supporting employee childcare needs or health coverage, or when hiring long-term unemployed workers,
etc.
4. Request for Data
20. This section discusses the type of information that we would like to obtain from countries. The
items to be considered are:
− Direct taxation of benefits;
− Tax breaks for social purposes;
4.1 Direct taxes and social security contributions on transfers
21. Across countries, information on direct tax (including Soc. Sec. Cont.) on transfer income can be
obtained from a variety of sources. These include: official administrative information; microsimulation
models based on annual income or monthly income; microsimulation based on survey data; adjustments
made on the basis of average tax rates based on microdatasets.
4.1.1 Administrative data
22. Ideally, administrative data is the preferred source of information of tax paid on benefit income
as such information is likely to be the most reliable. It may be feasible to obtain such information when
national social protection systems involve only a few taxable benefits (e.g. Germany), and/or when
completed tax forms allow for identification of tax paid on (some specified items of) transfer income. Also,
administrative information may give a picture of the aggregate of taxes paid on all public social cash
transfers, but not facilitate an allocation of tax paid on different types of transfers (e.g. unemployment vis-
à-vis pension benefits).
6
Question 1: Do you have administrative information on direct tax (including social security
contributions) paid on transfer income by benefit recipients. If yes, please complete Table Q1?
Table Q1.
Tax paid by benefit recipients on transfer income,
2020 to 2022
Amount
(in national currency)
Total tax paid (including soc. sec. cont.) on public1 transfer
income
of which:
- Income tax
- Social security contributions
Total tax paid (including soc. sec. cont.) on private1 transfer
income
of which:
- Income tax
- Social security contributions
1) Public transfer income concerns all cash benefits paid by general government (different levels of
government and social security institutions). Other social benefits, e.g. occupational pension
payments, are considered private.
Question 2: Do you have administrative information on direct tax (including social security
contributions) paid on specified transfer income items? If yes, please complete Table Q2 by
providing information at the greatest possible level of detail (e.g. by items as listed in Table Q3).
Table Q2.
Tax paid by benefit recipients on specific transfer income items,
2020 to 2022
Amount of tax
(including soc. sec. cont.) paid
(in national currency)
Total tax paid (including soc. sec. cont.) on transfer income
- item 1…
- item 2…
- item 3…
- etc.
For example, on basis of the US income-tax form, one could think of the
following list of items:
Total tax paid (including soc. sec. cont.) on transfer income
- item 1… - all social security benefits (OASDI)
- item 2… - unemployment compensation
- item 3… - pensions and annuities
- item 4 - Tax-advantaged individual retirement accounts
7
4.1.2 Estimates based on microdata sets
23. In the absence of administrative data, “microsimulation-models” and micro data sets (e.g. the
survey of personal incomes for the UK) which contain detailed information on both the incomes received
by households and their taxation can be used to generate average itemised tax rates (AITRs): e.g. the
average tax rate on public pension benefit or unemployment benefits. Indeed, the concept of AITRs has
been developed to facilitate identification of different tax levies on different social benefits. The AITR can
be defined as the total taxes paid by those receiving a given benefit, divided by the total income (from all
sources) of those receiving that benefit. Formally, the relevant calculations are:
AITR i = tu =1, n TI i/ tu=1, n I i
where: I is the amount of income-type “i”, and TI is the amount of tax paid on that particular amount of income, “i” is
the type or category of income, “tu” is a tax unit with income-type “i”, and “n” is the number of tax units in the
sample with income of type “i”. The broad income categories “i” include old-age cash benefits, unemployment
compensation, wage income, etc (see table Q3).
24. As is clear from the formula, calculation of the AITR requires information on the tax paid on
each particular benefit. If a given benefit is subject to a constant tax rate (possibly zero), this information is
straightforward to calculate. However, if it is subject to a progressive tax schedule (possibly applied to the
total of several income sources), the calculation needs more care. The methodology that we ask countries
to follow is to calculate the average tax rate a particular household faces on that income (or group of
incomes), as illustrated in Annex 1. This tax rate is applied to all household benefit income subject to the
progressive schedule. This methodology does not imply an ordering of different parts of income nor does it
require a more or less arbitrary decision on what part of household income should be “taxed” at a higher or
lower rate.
25. Depending on the nature of national social protection systems (the number of different social
programmes and taxable benefit payments) and the nature of information in microdatasets, the number of
identifiable AITRs will vary from country to country. Please complete Table Q3 in line with what is
possible given the source of information to which you have access.
Question 3: If your country has many taxable benefit items and administrative data do not allow for
identification of tax paid by benefit recipients of broad income groups, we ask you to generate
Average Itemised Tax rates per social expenditure programme (example line 1a in Table Q3) or
if this level of detail is not available the suggested broad social expenditure categories (for
example line 1 in Table Q3).
8
Table Q3.
Average Itemised Tax Rates,
2020 to 2022
Item
n° Broad Income Category 'i' 1
AITR
(%)
Amount of tax
(including soc. sec. cont.) paid
(in national currency)
1 Old-age cash benefits
1a - public pensions 2
1b - early retirement benefits
1c - private pensions 3
2 Survivors' benefits
2a - public pensions 2
2b - private pensions 3
3 Incapacity-related benefits
3a - Disability pensions
3b - Occupational Injury benefits
3c - Sickness payments 4
4 Family cash benefits
4a - Family benefits
4b - Maternity and parental leave payments
4c - Sole parent benefits
5 Active labour market policies
5a - benefits while on training
6 Unemployment
6a - unemployment insurance benefit
6b - unemployment assistance benefit
7 Housing
7a - rent subsidies
8 Other contingencies
8a - Low Income benefits
9 Wage income 5
1) Certain broad income categories may not apply to your country, please indicate. Not dissimilarly,
please indicate if pension income includes old-age cash benefits, survivor benefits and/or disability
pensions.
2) Public transfer income concerns all cash benefits paid by general government (different levels of
government and social security institutions). Other social benefits, e.g. occupational pension payments,
are considered private.
3) All pension income (old-age cash benefits) paid by the state or a social security fund.
4) If sickness benefits paid through social insurance funds (please indicate whether or not his covers
maternity and parental benefits in your data-set).
9
5) This category is included for reference purposes, but can be used to estimate tax paid by recipients of
continued wage payments in case of absence because of illness.
26. In some countries, ignoring local taxation may lead to underestimating the value of tax paid by
benefit recipients. In such cases, the preferred option is to “model” the situation analogous to Taxing
Wages (OECD, 2023). For example, for Switzerland, the situation in Canton Zürich could be used to
generate AITRs.
27. These AITRs are subsequently applied to the relevant spending items in the OECD Social
Expenditure Database leading to estimates of tax paid on particular spending items. Information derived
from microsimulation models/micro data sets can also be used to verify available administrative
information, or enrich it by adding more detail to its aggregate nature (see the previous section). In general,
the Secretariat will only publish aggregate indicators on net social expenditure, and differences taxes paid
across broad social expenditure items to illustrate the different tax burdens on different benefits.
4.2 Tax breaks with a social purpose
28. Please provide information on the revenue foregone of TBSPs other than pensions (see below) in
as much detail as possible in Table Q4, which includes different examples from different countries.
Question 4: Please provide information on the revenue foregone (accruals basis) of Tax Breaks for Social
Purposes in your country in Table Q4. Please note if you have already accounted for a Tax
breaks that is similar to cash benefits in the direct tax calculations, there is no need to record this
item again. If appropriate, please do include information on provincial and/or municipal TBSPs
and the revenue foregone related to including children in the tax unit.
10
Table Q4.
The value of Tax breaks for social purposes,
2020 to 2022
11
4.2.1 Tax treatment of pensions
29. The notion of tax breaks with a social purpose includes those measures aimed at stimulating
private pension take-up. However, tax breaks on occupational and individual pension programmes are
difficult to deal with as intervention (taxation and/or tax reliefs) occurs at, various stages of this form of
contractual savings. Tax treatment needs to be considered in three different areas:
30. Due to the complexity of calculations arising from these issues, there is no comparable data-set
available on the value of tax advantages on pensions. Nevertheless, available information suggests,
however, that the value of favourable tax-treatment of private pension arrangements can be considerable.
For example, in Germany and the United States such favourable tax treatment pensions was worth about
1% of GDP in 2019 and accounted for about 2% of GDP in Australia.( see detailed information on the
impact of the tax system on social expenditure by country) We would like to present the cost to public
budgets of the current tax system in the current financial year on tax breaks for pensions, regardless of
what effects the current tax system may have on revenues in future years. Because of the limitations in
comparability of information, such information would be presented as a memorandum item only.
Question 5: Please provide information on the revenue foregone (accruals basis) of Tax Breaks for
Pensions in your country in Table Q5.
Table Q5.
The value of Tax breaks for pensions,
2020 to 2022
− Contributions to programmes could be by employers or employees, out of taxed or untaxed income;
− The funds which invest the pension contributions on behalf of those contributing could be taxed or
untaxed;
− The payment of pension or annuity or lump-sum benefits at the end of the contributions period could
be taxed or untaxed.
12
ANNEX 1: AN EXAMPLE OF CALCULATING AVERAGE ITEMISED TAX RATES
Microsimulation models underlie the estimates on direct taxation of benefits in many countries,
especially when most transfer income is tax (e.g. Denmark and Sweden). It is relatively straightforward to
calculate average itemised tax rates (AITRs) on benefit income if households have only one source of
income. For example, if a retiree receives pension income worth 100 units at the “standard” tax rate of
20%, net transfer income is 80 units, and if all households were the same (and had no income from other
sources) the AITR on public pension income would be 20%. If the retiree were to receive non-taxable child
benefit, that income would be disregarded for the calculation of the tax rate on his/her household income,
while the AITR on child benefit would be nil for that country. It may well be that for older retirees (e.g.
over 75) a more favourable tax rate applies. If possible, it would be preferable to account for this age-
related measure while calculating the household tax rate, rather than it being separately treated as a tax
break with a social purpose.
Frequently pensioners receive income from different sources. Consider the case of a retiree who also
receives a supplementary (private) pension worth 50 Units. In the absence of progressivity in the tax
system, the household tax rate remains as before. However, the substantial increase of income may well
lead to the retiree being in a higher tax bracket, so that the “average” tax rate increases. This “higher” tax
rate is applied to all household income: different tax rates are not applied to different parts of household
income. (If the retiree were to receive child benefit that would be taxed at the same rate, unless the tax
benefit system explicitly regards this income as non-taxable). Thus, the methodology does not imply an
ordering of different parts of income, whereby different income sources are taxed differently according to
an arbitrary decision on which part of income is “basic” or “supplementary” (see Table A1). Differences in
AITRs are thus associated with income groupings wherein benefit recipients typically find themselves.
Table A1. Example of calculating AITRs on two types of income
household Basic
pension
Supplementary
pension
Total
household
income
Income
tax rate
Tax paid Allocation of tax over
pension income
components
Basic Supplementary
1 50 25 75 10% 7.5 5.0 2.5
2 75 50 125 15% 13.8 8.3 5.5
3 100 0 100 10% 10.0 10.0 0.0
4 50 100 150 15% 17.5 5.8 11.7
5 50 250 300 15% 40.0 6.7 33.3
Total 325 425 750 88.8 35.8 53
AITR basic pension income = tax paid over basic pension/total basic pension
income
11.1%
AITR supplementary pension income = tax paid over supplementary
pension/total supplementary pension income
12.5%
Assumed: standard tax rate is 10% when Income is less than 100 Units, and 15% of income over and above the 100 unit threshold.
13
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Adema, W., B. Eklind, J. Lotz, M. Einerhand and M. Pearson (1996), “Net Public Social Expenditure”,
Labour Market and Social Policy Occasional Papers, No. 19, OECD, Paris.
Adema, W. and M. Einerhand (1998), “The Growing Role of Private Social Benefits”, Labour Market and
Social Policy Occasional Paper, No. 32, OECD, Paris.
Adema, W. (1999), “Net Social Expenditure”, Labour Market and Social Policy Occasional Paper, No.
39, OECD, Paris
Adema, W. (2001), “Net Social Expenditure – 2nd edition”, Labour Market and Social Policy Occasional
Papers, No. 52, OECD, Paris.
Adema, W. and M. Ladaique (2005), “Net Social Expenditure, 2005 Edition”, Social, Employment and
Migration Working Papers, No. 29, Paris (www.oecd.org/els/workingpapers).
Adema, W. and M. Ladaique (2009), “How Expensive is the Welfare State? Gross and Net Indicators in
the OECD Social Expenditure Database (SOCX)”, OECD Social, Employment and Migration
Working Papers No. 92.
Adema, W, P.Fron and M. Ladaique (2011), Is the European Welfare State Really More Expensive?
Indicators on Social Spending, 1980-2012; and a Manual to the OECD Social Expenditure Database
(SOCX) Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers, No. 124, Paris
(www.oecd.org/social/expenditure.htm).
Adema, W, P.Fron (2019), The OECD SOCX Manual – 2019 edition
A guide to the OECD Social Expenditure Database (www.oecd.org/social/expenditure.htm)
OECD (1996), Tax Expenditures: Recent Experiences, Paris.
OECD (2023), Benefits and Wages, OECD, Paris and On-line Tax-Benefit calculator via
www.oecd.org/els/social/workincentives .
OECD (2023), The OECD Social Expenditure database (SOCX), www.oecd.org/social/expenditure.htm.
OECD (2023), Taxing Wages, Paris. (https://www.oecd.org/tax/taxing-wages-20725124.htm )
OECD (2023), Revenue Statistics 2023: Tax Revenue Buoyancy in OECD Countries, OECD Publishing,
Paris, https://doi.org/10.1787/2522770x.
Nimi | K.p. | Δ | Viit | Tüüp | Org | Osapooled |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Vastus | 28.02.2024 | 27 | 2-2/3479-2 | Kiri VÄLJA | ska | Rahandusministeerium |